What Is Price Discrimination, and How Does It Work?

What Is Price Discrimination?

Price discrimination is a selling strategy that charges customers different prices for the same product or service based on what the seller believes it can get the customer to agree to. In pure price discrimination, the seller charges each customer the maximum price they will pay. In more common forms of price discrimination, the seller segments customers into groups based on certain attributes and charges each group a different price.

Key Takeaways

  • With price discrimination, a seller charges different customers a different amount for the same product or service.
  • With first-degree discrimination, the company charges the maximum possible price for each unit consumed.
  • Second-degree discrimination involves discounts for products or services bought in bulk, while third-degree discrimination reflects different prices for different groups of consumers.
Price Discrimination

Investopedia / Theresa Chiechi

Understanding Price Discrimination

Price discrimination is practiced based on the seller's belief that customers in certain groups can be asked to pay more or less based on certain demographics or on how they value the product or service in question.

Price discrimination is most useful to sellers when the profit they earn as a result of separating the markets is greater than the profit that they would have earned had they kept the markets combined. Whether price discrimination works and how long the various groups will be willing to pay different prices for the same product depends on the relative elasticities of demand in the sub-markets. Consumers in a relatively inelastic sub-market may pay a higher price, while those in a relatively elastic sub-market pay a lower price.

In applying price discrimination, companies try to identify different market segments, such as domestic and industrial users, with different price elasticities. For example, Microsoft makes its Office 365 software available for a lower price to educators and educational institutions than to other users.

Markets must be kept separate by time, physical distance, or nature of use for price discrimination to be effective. Otherwise, consumers who purchase at a lower price in the elastic sub-market could resell at a higher price in the inelastic sub-market. Companies that dominate a particular market and use price discrimination strategies within their various sub-markets are known as discriminating monopolies.

While price discrimination has a long history, new tools, such as artificial intelligence, are changing the speed and effectiveness with which it is applied. As a 2021 article in the Harvard Business Review noted, "We're in a new era of supercharged price discrimination, made possible by two major scientific and technological trends. First, AI algorithms—often trained on highly detailed behavioral data—enable organizations to infer what people are willing to pay with unprecedented precision. Second, recent developments in behavioral science—often invoked with the tagline "nudge"—provide organizations greater ability to influence their customers' behaviors."

Price discrimination, as it is commonly practiced, is not illegal in the way that discrimination based on race, religion, gender, and similar factors is.

Types of Price Discrimination

There are three types of price discrimination: first-degree or perfect price discrimination, second-degree, and third-degree. These degrees of price discrimination are also known as personalized pricing (first-degree pricing), product versioning or menu pricing (second-degree pricing), and group pricing (third-degree pricing).

First-Degree Price Discrimination

First-degree discrimination, or perfect price discrimination, occurs when a business charges the maximum possible price for each unit consumed. Because prices vary among units, the firm captures all available consumer surplus for itself or the economic surplus. Many industries involving client services practice first-degree price discrimination, where a company charges a different price for every good or service sold.

Second-Degree Price Discrimination

Second-degree price discrimination occurs when a company charges a different price for different quantities consumed, such as quantity discounts on bulk purchases.

Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Third-degree price discrimination occurs when a company charges a different price to different groups of consumers. For example, a theater may divide moviegoers into seniors, adults, and children, each paying a different price when seeing the same movie. This type of price discrimination is the most common.

Examples of Price Discrimination

Many industries, such as the airline industry, the arts/entertainment industry, and the pharmaceutical industry, use price discrimination strategies. Examples of price discrimination include issuing coupons, applying specific discounts (e.g., age-based discounts), and creating loyalty programs for repeat customers.

In the airline industry, for example, people buying airline tickets several months in advance typically pay less than those purchasing at the last minute. When demand for a particular flight is high, airlines raise ticket prices in response.

By contrast, when tickets for a particular flight are not selling well, the airline will reduce the cost of available tickets to try to generate sales and fill any empty seats. Because many passengers prefer flying home late on Sunday, those flights tend to be more expensive than flights leaving early Sunday morning. Airline passengers will typically pay more for additional legroom, too.

Is Price Discrimination Illegal?

The word "discrimination" in price discrimination does not typically refer to something illegal or derogatory in most cases. Instead, it refers to firms being able to change the prices of their products or services dynamically as market conditions change, charging different users different prices for similar services, or charging the same price for services with different costs. Neither practice violates any U.S. laws—it would become unlawful only if it creates or leads to specific economic harm. 

Wouldn't Consumers Be Better Off if Everybody Paid the Same Price?

In many cases, no. Different customer segments have different characteristics and different price points that they are willing to pay. If everything were priced at say the "average cost," people with lower price points could never afford it. Likewise, those with higher price points could hoard it if they wished to. This is what is known as market segmentation. Economists have also identified market mechanisms whereby fixing static prices can lead to market inefficiencies from both the supply and demand sides.

When Can Companies Successfully Apply Price Discrimination?

Economists have identified three conditions that must be met for price discrimination to occur. First, the company needs to have sufficient market power. Second, it has to identify differences in demand based on different conditions or customer segments. Third, it must have the ability to protect its product from being resold by one customer group to another.

The Bottom Line

Price discrimination is a widespread practice across many different industries and is often invisible to the consumer. The buyers of a particular product or service may be unaware that the price they are paying is higher or lower than the one the seller is charging other buyers for it.

Article Sources
Investopedia requires writers to use primary sources to support their work. These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry experts. We also reference original research from other reputable publishers where appropriate. You can learn more about the standards we follow in producing accurate, unbiased content in our editorial policy.
  1. Microsoft. "Office 365 Education."

  2. Harvard Business Review. "How AI Can Help Companies Set Prices More Ethically."

Open a New Bank Account
×
The offers that appear in this table are from partnerships from which Investopedia receives compensation. This compensation may impact how and where listings appear. Investopedia does not include all offers available in the marketplace.
Part of the Series
Guide to Antitrust Laws