Profile Major Works Resources

L�on Walras, 1834-1910

The French economist Marie-�sprit L�on Walras (pronounced "Valrasse") has been hailed by Joseph Schumpeter as "the greatest of all economists" (Schumpeter, 1954: p.827). Walras was one of the three leaders of the Marginalist Revolution, even though his greatest work, Elements of Pure Economics, was published in 1874, three years after those of William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger.

Nonetheless, alone among the three revolutionaries, L�on Walras set forth the new "marginalist" or "Neoclassical" theory in a formal general equilibrium setting.   Thus, he endowed it with the multi-market considerations Jevons had largely avoided and the mathematical precision Menger had eschewed. L�on Walras is widely and rightfully regarded as the father of general equilibrium theory.

From any biography, the principal elements of Walras's life can be told.  He was the son of the French proto-marginalist economist and schoolteacher, Auguste Walras.  After spending a Bohemian youth in Paris as a novelist and art critic, L�on Walras soon followed his father's footsteps on almost every count: he adopted his father's socialist policy positions on taxation and land reform (in fact, he was a proponent of outright land nationalization) as well as his main ideas on economic theory (subjectivist theory of value, the mathematization of economics). After spending some unfruitful years in the cooperatives movement, Walras was appointed to the Academy of Lausanne in 1870.  It was there that he wrote and published the first edition of his magnum opus, the Elements of Pure Economics (1874).

L�on Walras's Elements should be familiar to every modern economist, as it encompasses much of what is available to us in modern general equilibrium theory.  Walras set out his Elements in progressive stages of complexity and generality.  Its eight parts can be briefly summarized:

  • (1) Walras provides his definition of the scope of economics, subjective value theory and the mathematical method;
  • (2) discusses two-commodity pure exchange where demand and supply are derived from utility-maximization; his "auctioneer" and the tatonnement process of stability is introduced here.
  • (3) introduces multi-market pure exchange; counts "equations and unknowns" to find existence; considers multi-market tatonnement with an auctioneer.
  • (4) incorporates production (in early editions, with fixed technology; in later editions, with flexible technology and thus marginal productivity theory) with a no-profit entrepreneur; shows how the demand for factors is derived as an indirect demand for goods (see the "Walras-Cassel" model).
  • (5) introduces his theory of capital; includes capitalization of future earnings and presents a theory of saving and credit;
  • (6) introduces his encaisse desir�e theory of money; sees money as providing future services and thus "desired" in a general choice problem;
  • (7) considers the continuous market and a growing economy.
  • (8) provides reflections on imperfect competition and monopoly.

In the aftermath of the Elements, Walras tried to build up a correspondence with virtually every important economist of the time, from America to Russia, in an effort to popularize his new theory. He found sympathizers and followers among several technically-gifted young Italians (e.g. Barone and Pareto) and Americans (e.g. Moore and Fisher). However, for the most part, he was largely ignored or dismissed by contemporary economists and mathematicians. 

In 1893, Walras was succeeded in his chair by his young disciple, Vilfredo Pareto.  The two men formed the core (and some argue the full extent) of what became known as the Lausanne School".  While they agreed on most theoretical matters, the details of the subsequent research program were dictated more by Pareto's interests than Walras's original concerns.

Walras had envisaged his 1874 Elements as part of a larger work. However, by the 1890s, Walras's mental capacities had begun to fail and it became doubtful that he would be able to complete this grand oeuvre in the manner he had originally intended  Walras hastily compiled two volumes,  Studies in Social Economics (1896) and the Studies in Applied Economics (1898).  Although little more than compilations of previously published articles, he still considered these books complementary to the Elements.   Tellingly, the 1874 Elements are subtitled "theory of social wealth", while his 1896 book is subtitled "theory of the division of social wealth" and his 1898 book "theory of the production of social wealth."  He regarded all three volumes as integral, indivisible and essential pillars for his general economic theory.  

Unfortunately, most economists dismissed these last two volumes as "light" stuff or, worse, a mere platform for socialist politics.  Today, as then, the Elements alone is regarded as his Walras's only "true" contribution.  However, some economists continue to believe that, because his other two volumes were not taken into account, modern Neo-Walrasian G.E. theory has not adhered to Walras's original vision, either in general purpose or in detail.  

Modern economists have also dismissed Walras's attempt, in a later (1896) edition of the Elements, to take credit for the discovery of the marginal productivity theory of distribution (and denouncing Wicksteed's claim to priority), not only as lacking any basis in truth but even as mean-spirited.  It is widely acknowledged that Walras learnt this theorem from Enrico Barone. (although, in a striking coincidence, Walras had been handed the theorem on a piece of paper from the Lausanne mathematician, Hermann Amstein, in 1877, but had not understood the mathematics well enough the make heads or tails out of it!) 

The last decade of Walras's life was spent in frustrated loneliness, bitter at the neglect of his work,  incapacitated by senility and mental illness. He died on January 5, 1910.

 

  


top1.gif (924 bytes)Top

Major Works of L�on Walras

  • Francis Saveur, 1858. [bk]
  • "De la propri�t� intellectuelle: position de la question �conomique", 1859, Journal des �conomistes (Dec), p.392
  • L'�conomie politique et la justice; Examen critique et r�futation des doctrines �conomiques de M. P.J. Produhon pr�c�des d'une introduction � l'�tude de la question sociale, 1860. [bk]
  • "Philosophie des sciences �conomiques", 1860, Journal des �conomistes, (v.25, Feb), p.196
  • "Paradoxes �conomiques I", 1860, Journal des �conomistes (v.28, Dec), p.373
  • Th�orie critique de l'imp�t, 1861. [bk]
  • De l'imp�t dans le Canton de Vaud, 1861. [bk]
  • Les Associations populaires de consommation, de production et de cr�dit, le�ons publiques faites � Paris le janvier et f�vrier 1865. 1865. [bk
  • "La bourse et le cr�dit", 1867, Paris Guide, p.1733
  • Recherche de l'id�al social: le�ons publiques faites � Paris, 1868 [bk]
  • "Principe d'une th�orie math�matique de l'�change", 1874, Journal des �conomistes, (v.34, Apr), p.5
  • �l�ments d'�conomie politique pure, ou th�orie de la richesse sociale, 1874 [bk]
    • Original 1874 edition: [bk]
    • Later French editions: [2nd ed., 1889], [3rd ed., 1896]; [4th ed. 1899] [revised "5th" ed. 1926]
    • English 1954 (W. Jaff�) translation of 1926 (5th ed): Elements of Pure Economics, or the theory of social wealth
    • English 2014 (D. Walker & J. van Daal) translation of 1896 (3rd ed:) Elements of Theoretical Economics, or the theory of social wealth [pdf].
  • "Th�orie math�matique de l'�change: Question de priorit�.  Correspondence entre M. Jevons, Professeur � Manchester et M. Walras, Professeur � Lausanne", 1874, Journal des �conomistes. (v.34, Jun), p.417
  • "Review of Antonio Errera's L'Italia Industriale", 1874, JdE, (v.36, Nov), p.329
  • "Un nuovo ramo della matematica.  Dell' applicazione delle matematiche all' economia politica", 1876, Giornale degli economisti. (An.2, v.3, Apr), p.1
  • Th�orie math�matique de bim�tallisme, 1881 (offprint of 1876/81)
  • "De la fixit� de valeur de l'�talon mon�taire", 1882,   Journal des �conomistes (Oct), p.5  [offprint]
  • Th�orie math�matique de la richesse sociale, 1883. [bk]
  • "D'une m�thode de r�gularisation de la variation de valeur de la monnaie", 1885, Mem Soc Vaudoise de sciences naturelles [offprint]
  • "Th�orie de la Monnaie", 1886, Revue scientifique, Pt. 1 (Apr 10, p.449), Pt.2 (Apr 17, p.493) [offprint]
  • Th�orie de la monnaie, 1886 [bk]
  • "Observations sur le principe de la theorie du prix de MM. Auspitz et Lieben", 1890, Rev dEP, p.320 [reply by Auspitz & Lieben, p.559]
  • "Notice autobiographique de L�on Walras", 1893. [first pub. 1965, v.1, cwp]
  • �tudes d'�conomie sociale; Th�orie de la r�partition de la richesse sociale, 1896. [bk]
  • "L'�tat et le chemin de fer", 1897, Revue du droit public et de la science politique, Pt. 1 (v.7, May-Jun, p.417), Pt. 2 (v.8, Jul-Aug, p.42) [McM]
  • �tudes d'�conomie politique appliqu�e; Th�orie de la production de la richesse sociale, 1898. [bk]
  • "Th�orie du cr�dit", 1898, Revue d'�conomie politique, p.128
  • "Sulle equazione della circulazione", 1899, Giornale degli economisti (Aug), p.110
  • "Cournot et l'�conomique Math�matique", 1905, Gazette de Lausanne (13 Jul)
  • "La Paix par la Justice Sociale et le Libre �change", 1907, Questions pratiques de L�gislation ouvri�re
  • "Leone Walras, Autobiografia", 1908, Giornale degli Economisti, p.603
  • "Un initiateur en �conomie politique, A.A. Walras", 1908, La Revue du Mois (v.6, Aug), p.170
  • "�conomique et m�chanique", 1909, Bulletin de la Societe Vaudoise de Sciences Naturelles.  [HET]

 


HET

 

top1.gif (924 bytes)Top

Resources on Leon Walras

Contemporary

Modern

 

 
top1.gif (924 bytes)Top
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

All rights reserved, Gon�alo L. Fonseca